consumption

consumption
/keuhn sump"sheuhn/, n.
1. the act of consuming, as by use, decay, or destruction.
2. the amount consumed: the high consumption of gasoline.
3. Econ. the using up of goods and services having an exchangeable value.
4. Pathol.
a. Older Use. tuberculosis of the lungs.
b. progressive wasting of the body.
[1350-1400; ME consumpcyon ( < MF) < L consumption- (s. of consumptio) a consuming, wasting, equiv. to consumpt(us), ptp. of consumere to CONSUME (con- CON- + sump- (var. s. of sumere to take up, spend) + -tus ptp. suffix) + -ion- -ION]
Syn. 1. depletion, exploitation, utilization.

* * *

In economics, the final using up of goods and services.

The term excludes the use of intermediate products in the production of other goods (e.g., the purchase of buildings and machinery by a business). Economists use statistical information on income and purchases to trace trends in consumption, seeking to map consumer demand for goods and services. In classical economics, consumers are assumed to be rational and to allocate expenditures in such a way as to maximize total satisfaction from all purchases. Incomes and prices are seen as consumption's two major determinants. Critics of the model point out that there are many exceptions to rational consumer behaviour
for example, the phenomenon of conspicuous consumption, in which the high price of a product increases its prestige and adds to demand.

* * *

Introduction

      in economics, the use of goods and services by households. Consumption is distinct from consumption expenditure, which is the purchase of goods and services for use by households. Consumption differs from consumption expenditure primarily because durable goods, such as automobiles, generate an expenditure mainly in the period when they are purchased, but they generate “consumption services” (for example, an automobile provides transportation services) until they are replaced or scrapped. (See consumer good.)

      Neoclassical (mainstream) economists generally consider consumption to be the final purpose of economic activity, and thus the level of consumption per person is viewed as a central measure of an economy's productive success.

      The study of consumption behaviour plays a central role in both macroeconomics and microeconomics. Macroeconomists are interested in aggregate consumption for two distinct reasons. First, aggregate consumption determines aggregate saving, because saving is defined as the portion of income that is not consumed. Because aggregate saving feeds through the financial system to create the national supply of capital, it follows that aggregate consumption and saving behaviour has a powerful influence on an economy's long-term productive capacity. Second, since consumption expenditure accounts for most of national output, understanding the dynamics of aggregate consumption expenditure is essential to understanding macroeconomic fluctuations and the business cycle.

      Microeconomists have studied consumption behaviour for many different reasons, using consumption data to measure poverty, to examine households' preparedness for retirement, or to test theories of competition in retail industries. A rich variety of household-level data sources (such as the Consumer Expenditure Survey conducted by the U.S. government) allows economists to examine household spending behaviour in minute detail, and microeconomists have also utilized these data to examine interactions between consumption and other microeconomic behaviour such as job seeking or educational attainment.

Consumption theory

The rational optimization framework
      In their studies of consumption, economists generally draw upon a common theoretical framework by assuming that consumers base their expenditures on a rational and informed assessment of their current and future economic circumstances. This “rational optimization” assumption is untestable, however, without additional assumptions about why and how consumers care about their level of consumption; therefore consumers' preferences are assumed to be captured by a utility function. For example, economists usually assume (1) that the urgency of consumption needs will decline as the level of consumption increases (this is known as a declining marginal utility of consumption), (2) that people prefer to face less rather than more risk in their consumption (people are risk-averse), and (3) that unavoidable uncertainty in future income generates some degree of precautionary saving. In the interest of simplicity, the standard versions of these models also make some less-innocuous assumptions, including assertions that the pleasure yielded by today's consumption does not depend upon on one's past consumption (there are no habits from the past that influence today's consumption) and that current pleasure does not depend upon comparison of one's consumption to the consumption of others (there is no “envy”).

      Within the rational optimization framework, there are two main approaches. The “life-cycle” model, first articulated in Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function (1954) by economists Franco Modigliani (Modigliani, Franco) and Richard Brumberg, proposes that households' spending decisions are driven by household members' assessments of expenditure needs and income over the remainder of their lives, taking into account predictable events such as a precipitous drop in income at retirement. The standard version of the life-cycle model also assumes that consumers would prefer to spend everything before they die (i.e., it assumes there is no bequest motive). Life-cycle models are most commonly employed by microeconomists modeling household-level data on consumption, income, or wealth.

      Macroeconomists tend to use a simplified version of the optimization framework called the “permanent income hypothesis,” whose origins trace back to economist Milton Friedman (Friedman, Milton)'s treatise A Theory of the Consumption Function (1957). The permanent income hypothesis omits the detailed treatment of demographics and retirement encompassed in the life-cycle model, focusing instead on the aspects that matter most for macroeconomic analysis, such as predictions about the nature of the consumption function, which relates consumer spending to factors such as income, wealth, interest rates, and the like.

      Perhaps the most important feature of the consumption function for macroeconomics is what it has to say about the marginal propensity to consume (propensity to consume) (MPC) when there are changes in income. Economist John Maynard Keynes (Keynes, John Maynard), who was the first to stress the importance of the MPC in The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936), believed that up to 90 percent of any increase in current income would translate into an immediate increase in consumption expenditure (an MPC of 90 percent). However, evidence has shown that Friedman's permanent income hypothesis is much nearer the mark: Friedman asserted that on average only about one-third of any windfall (a one-time unanticipated gain) would be spent within a year. He further argued that a one-for-one correlation between increased income and increased spending would occur only when the income increase was perceived to reflect a permanent change in circumstances (e.g., a new, higher-paying job).

      The modern mathematical versions of the life-cycle and permanent-income-hypothesis models used by most economists bring some plausible refinements to the original ideas. For example, the modern models imply that the marginal propensity to consume out of windfalls is much higher for poor than for rich households. This tendency makes it impossible to determine the impact of a tax cut or government program on consumption spending without knowing whether it is aimed primarily at low-wealth or high-wealth households. The theory further indicates that tax cuts or spending programs (such as extended unemployment benefits) aimed primarily at lower-income households should be considerably more effective at stimulating or maintaining aggregate spending than programs aimed at richer households.

Modifications to the standard framework
      In The Wealth of Nations (1776), Scottish economist Adam Smith (Smith, Adam) wrote:

A linen shirt…is, strictly speaking, not a necessary of life. The Greeks and Romans lived, I suppose, very comfortably though they had no linen. But in the present times, through the greater part of Europe, a creditable day-labourer would be ashamed to appear in public without a linen shirt, the want of which would be supposed to denote [a] disgraceful degree of poverty.

      Smith clearly did not believe one of the baseline assumptions built into the standard models of consumption described above: that the pleasure yielded by a given level of consumption is independent of the consumption standards of the surrounding community. A day labourer in Smith's time was a consumer of linen shirts for social as well as practical reasons. However, research into the consequences of this type of “comparison utility” suggests that observable individual spending behaviour is much the same whether one cares about absolute or relative levels of consumption, because there is nothing that the typical individual can do to change the consumption levels of others.

      If, however, the pleasure yielded by an individual's current consumption depends partly on a comparison to that person's past consumption habits, then rational consumers will realize that they will be happier if they increase their level of consumption gradually over their lifetimes (instead of equalizing consumption at different ages, as the life-cycle model suggests). Habit formation also implies a very different reaction to income shocks that reflects a gradual adaptation to new circumstances. The speed of adjustment depends on the strength of the habit. This is in contrast to Friedman's permanent income hypothesis, which assumes that a permanent shock (either negative or positive) will result in an immediate and complete adjustment of spending. A considerable amount of evidence from macroeconomic data seems to suggest that consumption does indeed react sluggishly to macroeconomic shocks.

      A final modification commonly made to the baseline life-cycle model is the abandonment of the assumption that people accumulate wealth solely to finance their own future spending. The high saving rates of the richest few percent of households (at least in the United States) are hard to explain in such a framework. The most popular solution is to incorporate a “bequest motive,” which explains the high saving rates of the very rich as resulting from beneficence toward their descendants. An alternative theory holds that some rich people gain satisfaction directly from the ownership of wealth, not merely from the happy contemplation of that wealth being spent by children, grandchildren, and so on. People might enjoy being wealthy for reasons of status, power, avarice, or other motivations that fall outside the traditional scope of economic analysis.

Alternatives to fully informed rationality
      The modifications just described pose no challenge to the premise that consumers are fully informed rational optimizers. The popularity of this assumption reflects the fact that there is usually only one way to behave rationally, but there are a great many possible ways to behave stupidly. In the absence of a general theory of stupidity, economists have been unable to construct a unified, compelling alternative to the rational optimization framework.

      Nonetheless, a few specific deviations from fully informed rationality have been explored. Evidence from experimental psychology suggests that people have difficulty resisting the impulse for instant gratification, even when they agree (at any time other than the exact moment of temptation) that it would be rational to resist. Whether such self-control problems have large economic effects is unclear. Economists have developed models showing that self-control problems have minor consequences if it is possible for consumers to make commitments that are difficult or troublesome to reverse—such as having an employer deduct a specified portion of an employee's paycheck for retirement savings before the money is deposited the employee's bank account (see 401(k)). It turns out that if such commitment strategies are available, they permit the consumer to achieve a lifetime consumption pattern very close to that predicted by the standard rational optimizing model, which makes no allowances for self-control problems or commitment mechanisms.

      Some distinctive implications, however, emerge in the model built on self-control problems. In particular, this model can explain seemingly illogical behaviour, such as holding a retirement savings account earning an interest rate of, say, 7 percent while simultaneously borrowing on credit cards and paying interest rates of up to 20 percent. Either the saving or the borrowing can be justified in the rational optimization framework (if we assume that savers are rational and patient while borrowers are rational but impatient), but the simultaneous practice of saving at a low interest rate and borrowing at a high interest rate is virtually impossible to reconcile within the rationality framework. This practice can be explained, however, by assuming that credit-card borrowing is the result of (largely) irrational impulse spending, while the retirement saving deductions are assumed to have been set up by the cool-headed, rational side of the consumer's nature.

      One other well-explored category of deviation from the standard framework simply drops the assumption that people are fully informed. Consumers who do not know whether a given shock to their incomes is transitory or permanent will tend to react as though there is some chance it is temporary and some chance that it is permanent. Alternatively, consumers who do not pay much attention to macroeconomic news may be slow to react when macroeconomic circumstances change (e.g., a recession). This category of theories may provide an alternative to habit formation as a means of explaining the sluggish reaction of consumption spending to economic news.

Consumption and the business cycle
      Private consumption expenditure accounts for about two-thirds of gross domestic product (GDP) in most developed countries, with the remaining one-third accounted for by business and government expenditures and net exports. A substantial portion of government expenditure (e.g., spending on public health programs) is also considered to be consumption expenditure, as it provides a service that consumers value.

      In national income accounting, private consumption expenditure is divided into three broad categories: expenditures for services, for durable goods, and for nondurable goods. Durable goods are generally defined as those whose expected lifetime is greater than three years, and spending on durable goods is much more volatile than spending in the other two categories. Services include a broad range of items including telephone and utility service, legal and financial services, and travel and lodging services. Nondurable goods include food and other immediately perishable items (sometimes called “strictly nondurable goods”) as well as some items that can be expected to last for a substantial period of time, such as clothing.

      The distinction between the flow of consumption as economists conceive it (including the services of durable goods owned by households) and consumption expenditure as measured in national income accounts is vital to understanding macroeconomic fluctuations. Producers (and therefore employers) make money only from the sale of a durable good, not from its continuing use after the sale. Therefore, it is the level of consumption expenditure—not the flow of consumption as defined above—that determines short-term macroeconomic prosperity (or otherwise).

      Macroeconomists have accordingly extended the rational optimization framework to account for the “lumpy” nature of durable goods (i.e., a large purchase is made in a single moment, but its usefulness extends over a long period; one cannot buy 1/20 of a new automobile). Both theory and evidence suggest roughly the following story. In an economic downturn, expenditures on durable goods such as automobiles generally plummet because many consumers who had been considering replacement of their durable goods decide to hold off either until the economy improves or until their need to replace the durable good becomes sufficiently urgent. The early phase of economic recoveries generally exhibits a surge in spending on durable goods as this process is reversed. More broadly, spending on durable goods tends to be much more volatile than spending on nondurables and services, because all that is needed to induce a surge in durables spending is something that pushes consumers from merely contemplating a purchase to actually making a purchase. This logic explains why spending on durables is much more sensitive to interest rates, rebates, and other economic stimuli than are other kinds of spending.

Christopher D. Carroll

Additional Reading
The impetus for the modern consumption literature comes largely from John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936); although Keynes's model of the consumption function has been superseded, there is still much wisdom in his discussion. The two classic references that form the foundation of the modern life-cycle and permanent-income theories of consumption are Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg, “Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function: An Interpretation of Cross-Section Data,” in Kenneth K. Kurihara (ed.), Post-Keynesian Economics (1954, reissued 1993), pp. 388–436; and Milton Friedman, A Theory of the Consumption Function (1957). An excellent summary of the literature can be found in Angus Deaton, Understanding Consumption (1992). An overview of the current baseline model and of the relationship between the mathematically rigorous versions of the life-cycle and permanent-income-hypothesis models is given in Christopher D. Carroll (1997), “Buffer-Stock Saving and the Life Cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(1):1–56 (1997).Perspectives that deviate from the current baseline framework have a venerable history, starting with Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776); of particular interest is chapter 2, where Smith argues that people care about how their consumption compares to that of others. Thorstein Veblen, The Theory of the Leisure Class (1899, reissued 1998), provides an extended treatment of this idea and introduces the phrase “conspicuous consumption.” Many related issues are discussed in Robert H. Frank, Choosing the Right Pond (1985). The introduction of Christopher D. Carroll, Jody Overland, and David N. Weil, “Saving and Growth with Habit Formation,” American Economic Review, 90(3):341–355 (2000), gives a summary of the evidence that habit formation may play an important role in explaining a wide variety of puzzles in macroeconomics. The seminal paper in the modern literature on self-control problems in consumption is David Laibson, “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2):443–477 (1997).Christopher D. Carroll

* * *


Universalium. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно решить контрольную?
Synonyms:

Look at other dictionaries:

  • consumption — con‧sump‧tion [kənˈsʌmpʆn] noun [uncountable] 1. COMMERCE ECONOMICS the amount of goods, services, energy, or natural materials used in a particular period of time: • Texas is second only to California in beer consumption. • Cuban households… …   Financial and business terms

  • Consumption — may refer to: Economics Use of final goods by a consumer until disposal Consumption (economics) Consumption function, an economic formula Consumption (ecology) Other Consumption, an archaic name for pulmonary tuberculosis ingestion of food and… …   Wikipedia

  • consumption — I noun confectio, consumptio, decay, decomposition, decrement, depletion, desolation, destruction, devastation, diminishment, diminution, dissipation, exhaustion, expenditure, loss, ravage, ruin, ruination, squandering, usage, use, using up,… …   Law dictionary

  • consumption — Consumption. sub. f. v. Il se dit de certaines choses que l on consume. Il se fait une grande consumption de bois dans cette maison. la victime fut bruslée jusques à son entiere consumption. la consumption des especes sacramentales. Il signifie… …   Dictionnaire de l'Académie française

  • Consumption — Con*sump tion (?; 215), n. [L. consumptio: cf. F. consomption.] 1. The act or process of consuming by use, waste, etc.; decay; destruction. [1913 Webster] Every new advance of the price to the consumer is a new incentive to him to retrench the… …   The Collaborative International Dictionary of English

  • consumption — sectors …   Dictionary of sociology

  • consumption — late 14c., wasting of the body by disease; wasting disease (replacing O.E. yfeladl the evil disease ), from O.Fr. consumpcion, from L. consumptionem (nom. consumptio) a using up, wasting, from consumpt , pp. stem of consumere (see CONSUME (Cf.… …   Etymology dictionary

  • consumption — in the meaning ‘a disease causing wasting of the tissues’, has been replaced in the 20c by more specific clinical names, especially by tuberculosis or TB …   Modern English usage

  • consumption — [n] devouring; use burning, consuming, damage, decay, decrease, depletion, desolation, destruction, devastation, diminution, dispersion, dissipation, drinking, eating, exhaustion, expenditure, loss, misuse, ruin, swallowing, using up, utilization …   New thesaurus

  • consumption — ► NOUN 1) the action or process of consuming. 2) an amount consumed. 3) dated a wasting disease, especially tuberculosis. DERIVATIVES consumptive adjective & noun (dated ) …   English terms dictionary

  • consumption — [kən sump′shən] n. [ME consumpcioun < OFr consomption < L consumptio < consumptus, pp. of consumere] 1. a) a consuming or being consumed b) Econ. the using up of goods or services, either by consumers or in the production of other goods… …   English World dictionary

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”