bureaucracy

bureaucracy
/byoo rok"reuh see/, n., pl. bureaucracies.
1. government by many bureaus, administrators, and petty officials.
2. the body of officials and administrators, esp. of a government or government department.
3. excessive multiplication of, and concentration of power in, administrative bureaus or administrators.
4. administration characterized by excessive red tape and routine.
[1810-20; BUREAU + -CRACY, modeled on F bureaucratie]

* * *

Professional corps of officials organized in a pyramidal hierarchy and functioning under impersonal, uniform rules and procedures.

Its characteristics were first formulated systematically by Max Weber, who saw in the bureaucratic organization a highly developed division of labour, authority based on administrative rules rather than personal allegiance or social custom, and a "rational" and impersonal institution whose members function more as "offices" than as individuals. For Weber, bureaucracy was a form of legalistic "domination" inevitable under capitalism. Later writers saw in bureaucracy a tendency to concentrate power at the top and become dictatorial, as occurred in the Soviet Union. Robert K. Merton emphasized its red tape and inefficiency due to blind conformity to procedures. More recent theories have stressed the role of managerial cliques, occupational interest groups, or individual power-seekers in creating politicized organizations characterized by internal conflict.

* * *

Introduction

      specific form of organization defined by complexity, division of labour, permanence, professional management, hierarchical coordination and control, strict chain of command, and legal authority. It is distinguished from informal and collegial organizations. In its ideal form, bureaucracy is impersonal and rational and based on rules rather than ties of kinship, friendship, or patrimonial or charismatic authority. Bureaucratic organization can be found in both public and private institutions.

Characteristics and paradoxes of bureaucracy
 The foremost theorist of bureaucracy is the German sociologist Max Weber (Weber, Max) (1864–1920), who described the ideal characteristics of bureaucracies and offered an explanation for the historical emergence of bureaucratic institutions. According to Weber, the defining features of bureaucracy sharply distinguish it from other types of organization based on nonlegal forms of authority. Weber observed that the advantage of bureaucracy was that it was the most technically proficient form of organization, possessing specialized expertise, certainty, continuity, and unity. Bureaucracy's emergence as a preferred form of organization occurred with the rise of a money-based economy (which ultimately resulted in the development of capitalism) and the attendant need to ensure impersonal, rational-legal transactions. Instrumental organizations (e.g., public-stock business firms) soon arose because their bureaucratic organization equipped them to handle the various demands of capitalist production more efficiently than small-scale producers.

      Contemporary stereotypes of bureaucracy tend to portray it as unresponsive, lethargic, undemocratic, and incompetent. Weber's theory of bureaucracy, however, emphasizes not only its comparative technical and proficiency advantages but also attributes its dominance as a form of organization to the diminution of caste systems (such as feudalism) and other forms of inequitable social relations based upon a person's status. In the pure form of bureaucratic organization universalized rules and procedures would dominate, rendering personal status or connections irrelevant. In this form, bureaucracy is the epitome of universalized standards under which similar cases are treated similarly as codified by law and rules, and under which the individual tastes and discretion of the administrator are constrained by due process rules. Despite the widespread derogatory stereotypes of bureaucracy, a system of government grounded in law requires bureaucracy to function.

      Nevertheless, the words bureaucracy and bureaucrat are typically thought of and used pejoratively. They convey images of red tape, excessive rules and regulations, unimaginativeness, a lack of individual discretion, central control, and an absence of accountability. Far from being conceived as proficient, popular contemporary portrayals often paint bureaucracies as inefficient and lacking in adaptability. Because the characteristics that define the organizational advantages of bureaucracy also contain within them the possibilities of organizational dysfunction, both the flattering and unflattering depictions of bureaucracy can be accurate. Thus, the characteristics that make bureaucracies proficient paradoxically also may produce organizational pathologies.

Jurisdictional competency
      Jurisdictional competency is a key element of bureaucratic organization, which is broken into units with defined responsibilities. Fundamentally, jurisdictional competency refers to bureaucratic specialization, with all elements of a bureaucracy possessing a defined role. The responsibilities of individuals broaden with movement upward through an organizational hierarchy. The organizational division of labour (labour, division of) enables units and individuals within an organization to master details and skills and to turn the novel into the routine. Although the division of labour is highly efficient, it can lead to a number of harmful organizational pathologies; for example, units or individuals may be unable to identify and respond adequately to problems outside their competency and may approach all problems and priorities exclusively from the purview of a unit's specific capabilities. This feature of bureaucracy also can lead organizational units to shirk responsibility by allowing them to define a problem as belonging to some other unit and thereby leave the issue unattended. Alternatively, every unit within an organization is apt to put a face on a problem congenial mainly to its own interests, skills, and technologies.

Command and control
      Bureaucracies have clear lines of command and control. Bureaucratic authority is organized hierarchically, with responsibility taken at the top and delegated with decreasing discretion below. Because of the risk of organizational parochialism produced by limited and specific jurisdictional competencies, the capacity to coordinate and control the multiplicity of units is essential. Authority is the glue that holds together diversity and prevents units from exercising unchecked discretion. Yet, few features of bureaucratic life have received so much adverse attention as the role of hierarchical authority as a means for achieving organizational command and control. Popular criticisms emphasize that hierarchical organization strangles creative impulses and injects hyper-cautious modes of behaviour based on expectations of what superiors may desire. Command and control, which are necessary to coordinate the disparate elements of bureaucratic organization, provide for increasing responsibility upward, delegation, and decreasing discretion downward.

Continuity
      Continuity is another key element of bureaucratic organization. Rational-legal authority necessitates uniform rules and procedures for written documents and official behaviour. A bureaucracy's files (i.e., its past records) provide it with organizational memory, thereby enabling it to follow precedent and standard operating procedures. The ability to utilize standard operating procedures makes organizations more efficient by decreasing the costs attached to any given transaction. Organizational files record procedures, antecedent behaviour, and personnel records. They also allow an organization to be continuous and, thus, independent of any specific leadership. On the whole, continuity is vital to an organization's capacity to retain its identity and even its culture. Without its records, it would be impossible to maintain transactions grounded in legality. Yet continuity also has a dysfunctional side, leading organizations to behave predictably and conservatively or, worse perhaps, merely reflexively. Continuity also may lead a bureaucracy to repeat regularly activities that may be inaccurate and whose inaccuracies thereby cumulate.

Professionalization
      Professionalization of management, another basic element of bureaucracy, requires a full-time corps of officials whose attention is devoted exclusively to its managerial responsibilities. In government, professionalization is vested in the corps of civil servants (civil service) whose positions have generally been obtained through the passage of tests based upon merit. The civil service is sometimes considered a permanent government, distinct from the transient politicians who serve only for a limited time and at the pleasure of the electorate in democratic political systems.

      In businesses and in other nongovernmental bureaucratic organizations, there is also a professional cadre of managers. Professionalization increases expertise and continuity within the organization. Even when organizations are temporarily leaderless or experience turmoil in their top leadership positions, the professional cadre helps to maintain an organizational equilibrium. The virtues of professionalization are clear; without a professional corps, organizations would suffer from crises induced by incompetency. Professionalization thus contributes to the superior technical proficiency that Weber claimed was the hallmark of bureaucratic organization.

      Despite its virtues, professionalization also carries potential risks. Often the professional corps of managerial experts itself becomes a covert source of power because it has superior knowledge compared to those who are its nominal but temporary superiors. By virtue of greater experience, mastery of detail, and organizational and substantive knowledge, professional bureaucrats may exercise strong influence over decisions made by their leaders. The existence of powerful bureaucrats raises issues of accountability and responsibility, particularly in democratic systems; bureaucrats are supposedly the agents of their leaders, but their superior knowledge of detail can place them in a position of indispensability. In addition, although a permanent corps of officials brings expertise and mastery of detail to decision making, it also deepens the innate conservatism of a bureaucracy. The permanent corps is usually skeptical of novelty because the essence of bureaucratic organization is to turn past novelties into present routines. Professional bureaucrats, be they in the civil or private sector, also tend to favour the organizational status quo because their investments (e.g., training and status) are tied to it. Consequently, the more professionalized the cadre becomes, the more likely it is to resist the intrusion of external forces.

Rules
      Rules are the lifeblood of bureaucratic organization, providing a rational and continuous basis for procedures and operations. An organization's files provide the inventory of accumulated rules. Bureaucratic decisions and—above all—procedures are grounded in codified rules and precedents. Although most people dislike rules that inhibit them, the existence of rules is characteristic of legal-rational authority, ensuring that decisions are not arbitrary, that standardized procedures are not readily circumvented, and that order is maintained. Rules are the essence of bureaucracy but are also the bane of leaders who want to get things done their way instantly.

      Rules restrain arbitrary behaviour, but they also can provide formidable roadblocks to achievement. The accumulation of rules sometimes leads to the development of inconsistencies, and the procedures required to change any element of the status quo may become extraordinarily onerous as a result of the rule-driven character of bureaucracy. One perspective holds that the strict adherence to rules restricts the ability of a bureaucracy to adapt to new circumstances. By contrast, markets, which can operate with very few rules, force rapid adaptation to changing circumstances. Yet, most major business organizations are arranged in bureaucratic form because hierarchy and delegated responsibility reduce the transaction costs of making decisions.

Summary
      Thus, the most basic elements of pure bureaucratic organization are its emphasis on procedural regularity, a hierarchical system of accountability and responsibility, specialization of function, continuity, a legal-rational basis, and fundamental conservatism. The emergence of capitalism and the emphasis on standard currency transactions over and above barter systems created the need for bureaucratic forms of organization in both the private and public sectors. However, the critical elements of the bureaucratic form of organization also can conflict with one another and are often at the base of criticisms that regard bureaucracies as dysfunctional. In sum, what makes bureaucracy work also may work against it.

Bureaucracy and the state
      All forms of governance (government) require administration, but only within the past few centuries has the bureaucratic form become relatively common. Although Weber observed bureaucratic forms of administration in ancient Egypt, during the later stages of the Roman Empire, in the Roman Catholic Church, and in imperial China, the rise of the modern nation-state was accompanied by a commensurate elevation in the status of its administration, the bureaucratization of the administration, and the indispensability of its permanent officialdom. The bureaucracy, in service to the crown, was the manifestation of the state. Building the state essentially was identified with the increasing proficiency of its bureaucratic apparatus and the status of its permanent officials.

      The development of public bureaucracy generally accompanied the capacity of a state to extend its reach and to unite its territories under a single sovereignty. The establishment of a full-time administrative cadre was a sign of a government's administrative unity and its capacity to implement its writ. The bureaucratization of the state, odd as it may initially seem, typically provided the basis for its democratization because it eliminated feudal, plutocratic, and patrimonial bases of administration. Some states, typically those that experienced a struggle to break the power base of a provincial aristocracy, developed a strong professional bureaucracy to serve the crown and unify the state. During the reign of Louis XIV (1643–1715), France established a strong professional corps of officials responsible for public works, extracting revenues, and otherwise supporting the ambitions of the crown. The term bureaucracy was coined (as bureaucratie) in the mid-18th century by French philosophe Vincent de Gournay, derived from the French bureau, meaning writing desk, and -cratie, meaning government. In the 19th century the Meiji Restoration in Japan (1868–1912), motivated by powerful modernizing ambitions, centralized the state, weakened the aristocracy, and created a powerful bureaucracy. By contrast, Britain's more powerful aristocracy continued to wield amateur administrative functions until well into the 19th century, when a professionalized civil service eventually emerged. In the United States a professional civil service was not created at the federal level until 1883, and in many of its states and localities not until much later. The actual realization of a modern bureaucracy at the federal level in the United States was a patchwork, reflecting responses to specific problems and its complicated system of political authority.

      Traditionally, governments have reformed their administrative operations in response to evident failures (e.g., the inability to deal with crises or to function effectively in warfare) and the need to create universal systems of benefits (e.g., pensions, health care, and education), both of which require revenue extraction by an efficient institution. Until the end of the 20th century, administrative reforms generally strengthened the meritocratic and universalistic bases of administrative organization to guard against the malignant influences of corruption, a lack of accountability, and patronage. However, by the 1980s reform efforts in established democracies gained momentum, emphasizing decentralization and market-based decision making and, in some instances, even the replacement of full-time civil servants with managers on contract. In order to increase flexibility and adaptability and to make the public sphere leaner and performance-oriented, the debureaucratization of the state's administrative apparatus became fashionable, if not comprehensively applied. These reforms often fall under the rubric of what is called New Public Management.

      The administrative apparatus of the state in developing countries, however, rarely has come close to achieving the impersonal, rule-based status that Weber depicted. Nor has it generally been able to produce the level of proficiency that Weber claimed was characteristic of bureaucracy. Often the lack of sufficient resources to pay officials in resource-scarce societies has led to corruption and, at the very least, shirking on the job so that officials can tend to other, more remunerative ventures. The absence of a strong professionalized corps of officials in such settings has meant that the civil service is often a source of patronage, allowing leaders to pay off supporters or deter the formation of an opposition. As these countries generally lack adequate resources, the state bureaucracy has less to extract to allow for the proficient delivery of services.

      Many of the problems identified in developing countries, of course, affect even the most affluent countries, though usually to a lesser degree. The extent to which bureaucracy performs in accordance with the Weberian characterization is related to the external circumstances governing its capabilities. As a consequence, when these resources are lacking or when there is little basis for the rule of rational-legal authority, the state bureaucracy is unable to act in ways that may make it accountable, proficient, or rule-based. Further, when pay is low and educational resources limited, the officials responsible for running the administrative machinery may have inadequate skills and become susceptible to corruption and shirking. Thus, the fact that the administrative apparatus of a state is casually referred to as “the bureaucracy” (or its officials as “bureaucrats”) says little about how proximate to or distant from the Weberian ideal of bureaucracy it is.

      In developing countries ideas about administrative reform often move in the direction of the more formalistic Weberian ideal—particularly the creation of universalistic standards, regular procedures, and accountability. By contrast, in more-affluent countries, there is some emphasis, particularly but not exclusively in the largely English-speaking democracies, to reduce administrative formalism associated with bureaucracy, diminish the number of rules, and increase discretion and performance accountability lower down in organizations. Whereas in developing countries the main need is the reduction of corruption, in more established countries the reform motif is focused on rapid adaptability and performance. In settings where the state bureaucracy is believed to have been essential to the identity and performance of the state itself (e.g., France and Germany), there is more resistance to the introduction of market criteria to evaluate the state administrative apparatus or to disrupt prevailing patterns of civil service recruitment and training.

Trends in bureaucratic organization
      Empirical studies of ostensibly bureaucratic organizations have often revealed a rich informal life within them that is at odds with the formal chain-of-command depictions. The classic work Administrative Behavior, originally published in 1947 from the doctoral dissertation of Herbert Simon (Simon, Herbert A.), dissected the vintage bureaucratic paradigm and concluded that it was frequently inconsistent with psychological and social realities. Workers on production lines, for example, often generated their own norms that produced suboptimal results for the organization. In reality, the Weberian ideal of bureaucratic organization is frequently imperfect.

      The terms bureaucracy and bureaucrat are often loosely employed as interchangeable with any form of administrative organization, however distant its pattern of behaviour from the Weberian model. Frequently, therefore, criticisms of bureaucracy and bureaucrats are criticisms of administrative behaviour that departs significantly from the ideals of bureaucratic organization and the professionalism of its corps of officials. Still, bureaucracy has been challenged by more informal and adaptive modes of organization (e.g, markets, networks, and other less hierarchical or rules-driven modalities of organization). As no other form of organization allows for the regularity and accountability characterized by the bureaucratic form, however, it is unlikely that the bureaucratic form of organization will be supplanted.

Bert Rockman

Additional Reading
A clear and concise English-language version of the Weberian ideal-form characterization of bureaucracy and an explanation for its emergence can be found in the chapter “Bureaucracy” in H.H. Gerth and C.W. Mills (eds. and trans.), From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology (1970), pp. 196–244. An effort to examine the classic and revised conceptions of distinctions between bureaucratic and political thinking through extensive interviews with bureaucrats and politicians in western Europe and the United States is found in Joel D. Aberbach, Robert D. Putnam, and Bert A. Rockman, Bureaucrats and Politicians in Western Democracies (1981).Historical forces pushing for (and against) the bureaucratization of the state in Europe are analyzed in John A. Armstrong, The European Administrative Elite (1973), chapters 1–4 and 13–14.The American version of the global New Public Management syndrome is expressed in the report of the National Performance Review, From Red Tape to Results: Creating A Government That Works Better and Costs Less (1993), a report under the direction of then Vice President Al Gore. It emphasizes that bureaucratic organization was built for the industrial age and that new forms of sleeker, highly flexible organization are required for the information age. A careful appraisal of the benefits and defects of the review is Donald F. Kettl, Reinventing Government? Appraising the National Performance Review (1994).A brief but compelling book emphasizing the rules and regulations that inhibit bureaucracy is Herbert Kaufman, Red Tape: Its Origins, Uses, and Abuses (1977). An early study of how informal groups flourish inside industrial organization and circumvent the formal rules through the construction of informal norms is F.J. Roethlisberger and William J. Dickson, Management and the Worker (1939). The analytic foundations of how choices are made in bureaucratic organization are shown in Herbert A. Simon, Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization, third edition, 4th ed. (1997), originally published in 1947 from the Nobel Prize-winning author's doctoral dissertation (1941).The development of the American bureaucratic state is discussed in Stephen Skowronek, Building A New American State, 1870–1920 (1982). The central role of the bureaucracy in state-building in France is explored in Ezra N. Suleiman, Elites in French Society: The Politics of Survival (1978).Bert Rockman

* * *


Universalium. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать курсовую

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Bureaucracy — is the structure and set of regulations in place to control activity, usually in large organizations and government. As opposed to adhocracy, it is represented by standardized procedure (rule following) that dictates the execution of most or all… …   Wikipedia

  • bureaucracy — bu‧reauc‧ra‧cy [bjʊəˈrɒkrəsi ǁ bjʊˈrɑː ] noun bureaucracies PLURALFORM 1. [countable] a system of government that uses a large number of departments and officials: • a powerful centralized bureaucracy 2. [uncountable] disapproving all the… …   Financial and business terms

  • Bureaucracy — ist ein Textadventure von Infocom aus dem Jahr 1987, das u. a. von Douglas Adams geschrieben wurde. Inhaltsverzeichnis 1 Handlung 2 Beilagen 3 Anmerkungen 4 Literatur …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • bureaucracy — I noun administration, agency, authorities, delegated authority, departmentalization, governance, government, government by bureaus, government office, governmental procedure, governmental system for decision making, inflexible routine,… …   Law dictionary

  • bureaucracy — 1818, from Fr. bureaucratie, from bureau office, lit. desk (see BUREAU (Cf. bureau)) + Gk. suffix kratia denoting power of; coined by Fr. economist Jean Claude Marie Vincent de Gournay (1712 1759) on model of democratie, aristocratie. That vast… …   Etymology dictionary

  • Bureaucracy — Bu*reau cra*cy, n. [Bureau + Gr. ? to be strong, to govern, ? strength: cf. F. bureaucratie.] 1. A system of carrying on the business of government by means of departments or bureaus, each under the control of a chief, in contradiction to a… …   The Collaborative International Dictionary of English

  • bureaucracy — [n] system which controls organization administration, authority, beadledom*, city hall*, civil service, directorate, government, management, ministry, officialdom, officials, powers that be*, red tape*, regulatory commission, the Establishment* …   New thesaurus

  • bureaucracy — ► NOUN (pl. bureaucracies) 1) a system of government in which most decisions are taken by state officials rather than by elected representatives. 2) excessively complicated administrative procedure. DERIVATIVES bureaucratization (also… …   English terms dictionary

  • bureaucracy — [byoo rä′krə sē, byo͞orä′krə sē] n. pl. bureaucracies [Fr bureaucratie < BUREAU + cratie, CRACY] 1. the administration of government through departments and subdivisions managed by sets of appointed officials following an inflexible routine 2 …   English World dictionary

  • bureaucracy — A body of administrative officials, and the procedures and tasks involved in a particular system of administration, for example a state or formal organization. Max Weber did not invent the concept of bureaucracy (the term was coined in France at… …   Dictionary of sociology

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”