Malthus, Thomas Robert

Malthus, Thomas Robert
born Feb. 14/17, 1766, Rookery, near Dorking, Surrey, Eng.
died Dec. 23, 1834, St. Catherine, near Bath, Somerset

British economist and demographer.

Born into a prosperous family, he studied at the University of Cambridge and was elected a fellow of Jesus College in 1793. In 1798 he published An Essay on the Principle of Population, in which he argued that population will always tend to outrun the food supply
that the increase of population will take place, if unchecked, in a geometrical progression, while the means of subsistence will increase only in an arithmetical progression. He believed population would expand to the limit of subsistence and would be held there by famine, war, and ill health. He enlarged on his ideas in later editions of his work (to 1826). He argued that relief measures for the poor should be strictly limited since they tended to encourage the growth of excess population. His theories, though largely disproven, had great influence on contemporary social policy and on such economists as David Ricardo.

* * *

▪ English economist and demographer
Introduction
born Feb. 14/17, 1766, Rookery, near Dorking, Surrey, England
died Dec. 23, 1834, St. Catherine, near Bath, Somerset
 English economist and demographer who is best known for his theory that population growth will always tend to outrun the food supply and that betterment of humankind is impossible without stern limits on reproduction. This thinking is commonly referred to as Malthusianism.

Academic development
      Malthus was born into a prosperous family. His father, a friend of the philosopher and skeptic David Hume (Hume, David), was deeply influenced by Jean-Jacques Rousseau (Rousseau, Jean-Jacques), whose book Émile (1762) may have been the source of the elder Malthus's liberal ideas about educating his son. The young Malthus was educated largely at home until his admission to Jesus College, Cambridge, in 1784. There he studied a wide range of subjects and took prizes in Latin and Greek, graduating in 1788. He earned his master of arts degree in 1791, was elected a fellow of Jesus College in 1793, and took holy orders in 1797. His unpublished pamphlet “The Crisis,” written in 1796, supported the newly proposed Poor Laws (Poor Law), which recommended establishing workhouses (workhouse) for the impoverished. This view ran somewhat counter to the views on poverty and population that Malthus published two years later.

Professional achievements
      In 1804 Malthus married Harriet Eckersall, and in 1805 he became a professor of history and political economy at the East India Company's college at Haileybury, Hertfordshire. It was the first time in Great Britain that the words political economy had been used to designate an academic office. Malthus lived quietly at Haileybury for the remainder of his life, except for a visit to Ireland in 1817 and a trip to the Continent in 1825. In 1811 he met and became close friends with the economist David Ricardo (Ricardo, David).

      In 1819 Malthus was elected a fellow of the Royal Society; in 1821 he joined the Political Economy Club, whose members included Ricardo and James Mill (Mill, James); and in 1824 he was elected one of the 10 royal associates of the Royal Society of Literature. In 1833 he was elected to the French Académie des Sciences Morales et Politiques and to the Royal Academy of Berlin. Malthus was one of the cofounders, in 1834, of the Statistical Society of London.

Malthusian theory
      In 1798 Malthus published anonymously the first edition of An Essay on the Principle of Population as It Affects the Future Improvement of Society, with Remarks on the Speculations of Mr. Godwin, M. Condorcet, and Other Writers.The work received wide notice. Briefly, crudely, yet strikingly, Malthus argued that infinite human hopes for social happiness must be vain, for population will always tend to outrun the growth of production. The increase of population will take place, if unchecked, in a geometric progression, while the means of subsistence will increase in only an arithmetic progression. Population will always expand to the limit of subsistence and will be held there by famine, war, and ill health. “Vice” (which included, for Malthus, contraception), “misery,” and “self-restraint” alone could check this excessive growth.

      Malthus's thought reflects a reaction, amiably conducted, to his father's views and to the doctrines of the French Revolution and its supporters, such as the English radical philosopher William Godwin (Godwin, William). Widely read for such works as Political Justice (1793), Godwin took for granted the perfectibility of humankind and looked to a millennium in which rational people would live prosperously and harmoniously without laws and institutions. Unlike Godwin (or, earlier, Rousseau), who viewed human affairs from a theoretical standpoint, Malthus was essentially an empiricist and took as his starting point the harsh realities of his time. His reaction developed in the tradition of British economics, which would today be considered sociological.

      Malthus was an economic pessimist, viewing poverty as man's inescapable lot. The argument in the first edition of his work on population is essentially abstract and analytic. After further reading and travels in Europe, Malthus produced a subsequent edition (1803), expanding the long pamphlet of 1798 into a longer book and adding much factual material and illustration to his thesis. At no point, even up to the final and massive sixth edition of 1826, did he ever adequately set out his premises or examine their logical status. Nor did he handle his factual and statistical materials with much critical or statistical rigour, even though statisticians in Europe and Great Britain had developed increasingly sophisticated techniques during Malthus's lifetime. American sociologist and demographer Kingsley Davis (Davis, Kingsley) remarked that, while Malthus based his theories on a strong empirical foundation, the theories tended to be weakest in their empiricism and strongest in their theoretical formulation. For better or worse, the Malthusian theory of population was, nevertheless, incorporated into theoretical systems of economics. It acted as a brake on economic optimism, helped to justify a theory of wages based on the wage earner's minimum cost of subsistence, and discouraged traditional forms of charity.

      The Malthusian theory of population made a strong and immediate impact on British social policy. It had been believed that fertility itself added to national wealth; the Poor Laws (Poor Law) perhaps encouraged large families with their doles. If they had “never existed,” wrote Malthus, “though there might have been a few more instances of severe distress, the aggregate mass of happiness among the common people would have been much greater than it is at present.” These laws limited the mobility of labour, he said, and encouraged fecundity and should be abolished. For the most unfortunate it might be reasonable to establish workhouses—not “comfortable asylums” but places in which “fare should be hard” and “severe distress . . . find some alleviation.”

      He continued publishing a variety of pamphlets and tracts on economics. In an approach less rigorous than Ricardo's, Malthus discussed the problem of price determination in terms of an institutionally determined “effective demand,” a phrase that he invented. In his summary Principles of Political Economy Considered with a View to Their Practical Application (1820), Malthus went so far as to propose public works and private luxury investment as possible solutions for economic distress through their ability to increase demand and prosperity. He criticized those who valued thrift as a virtue knowing no limit; to the contrary, he argued that “the principles of saving, pushed to excess, would destroy the motive to production.” To maximize wealth, a nation had to balance “the power to produce and the will to consume.” In fact, Malthus, as an economist concerned with what he called the problem of “gluts” (or, as they would be called today, the problems of economic recession or depression), can be said to have anticipated the economic discoveries made by John Maynard Keynes in the 1930s.

      Then again, a fundamental criticism of Malthus was his failure to anticipate the agricultural revolution, which caused food production to meet or exceed population growth and made prosperity possible for a larger number of people. For example, the price of wheat in the United States, adjusted for inflation, has fallen by about two-thirds in the last 200 years. Since 1950, the world's per capita food production has increased by about 1 percent per year. The incidence of famine has diminished, with famines in the modern era typically caused by war or by destructive government policies, such as price controls on food. Malthus also failed to anticipate the widespread use of contraceptives that brought about a decline in the fertility rate.

Donald Gunn MacRae

Additional Reading
W. Otter, “Memoir,” preface to the 2nd ed. of the Principles of Political Economy (1836), is still a basis for any biography. James Bonar, Malthus and His Work (1885, reprinted and expanded 1924, reprinted 1966), is the major work of 19th-century scholarship, illuminated by very wide learning. John Maynard Keynes, “Robert Malthus: The First of the Cambridge Economists,” in Essays in Biography (new ed., 1951, reissued 1963), is charming and of great importance in the rehabilitation of Malthus as a major economic theorist. D.V. Glass (ed.), Introduction to Malthus (1953, reissued 1959), contains “A Summary View of the Principle of Population,” an important letter on the Poor Laws by Malthus, a very full bibliography on the Malthusian question in the 19th century, and three useful essays discussing Malthus in historical perspective. Anthony Flew, “The Structure of Malthus' Population Theory,” Australasian Journal of Philosophy, 35:1–20 (1957), and the same author's edited version of Malthus's An Essay on the Principle of Population (1970, reissued 1985), were contributed by a critic and philosopher who has brought both logical rigour and sympathy to the clarification of Malthus's analysis. Philip Morris Hauser and Otis Dudley Duncan (eds.), The Study of Population: An Inventory and Appraisal (1959, reissued 1964), though partly out of date, is a most useful single introduction to modern population studies and the issues raised by Malthus. Kenneth Smith, The Malthusian Controversy (1951, reprinted 1978); and D.E.C. Eversley, Social Theories of Fertility and the Malthusian Debate (1959, reprinted 1975), are two admirable and scholarly discussions of all the issues surrounding the Malthusian population theory. Also useful is Julian L. Simon, The Ultimate Resource 2 (1996, reissued 1998).

* * *


Universalium. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно сделать НИР?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Malthus,Thomas Robert — Mal·thus (mălʹthəs), Thomas Robert. 1766 1834. British economist who wrote An Essay on the Principle of Population (1798), arguing that population tends to increase faster than food supply, with inevitably disastrous results, unless the increase… …   Universalium

  • Malthus, Thomas Robert — (1766–1834)    An Anglican clergyman, prominent political economist, and author of the doctrine that constricted food supplies must determine economic life. He had an unconventional education, for a clergyman, at a dissenting academy, and then at …   Encyclopedia of the Age of Imperialism, 1800–1914

  • Malthus, Thomas Robert — (1766 1834) An early political economist whose Essay on Population, first published in 1798 and frequently revised, had an enormous impact on theories of population. Malthus s father, a liberal English landowner and a friend of Rousseau ,… …   Dictionary of sociology

  • Malthus, Thomas Robert — (1766–1834) English social theorist. Although belonging principally to the history of science, Malthus s Essay on Populations (1798) was philosophically influential in undermining the Enlightenment belief in unlimited possibilities of human… …   Philosophy dictionary

  • Malthus, Thomas Robert —   in geography, renowned for his theory of population as it relates to resources. Based on the principles that food production increases at an arithmetic rate, whereas population increases at an exponential rate, Malthus stated that population… …   Geography glossary

  • Malthus, Thomas Robert — ► (1766 1834) Economista británico. Su principal estudio es el Ensayo sobre los principios de la población (1798), en el que afirmaba que la población tiende a crecer en progresión geométrica, mientras que los alimentos solo aumentan en… …   Enciclopedia Universal

  • MALTHUS, Thomas Robert — (1766 1834)    English economist and Curate at Albury, Surrey (1798). Aroused controversy by the argument he put forth in his book An Essay on the Principle of Population (1798), in which he predicted inevitable famine …   Concise dictionary of Religion

  • Malthus, Thomas Robert — (1766 1834)    Economist, s. of a landed proprietor, was b. near Dorking, and ed.. at Jesus Coll., Camb., of which he became a Fellow. Taking orders he became incumbent of Albury, Essex. He travelled much on the continent, collecting information… …   Short biographical dictionary of English literature

  • Thomas Robert Malthus — Malthus redirects here. For demon, see Malthus (demon). Thomas Robert Malthus Classical economics Thomas Robert Malthus Born February 14 …   Wikipedia

  • Thomas Robert Malthus — Thomas Malthus Thomas Robert Malthus Naissance 13 février 1766 Dorking, dans le Surrey (Royaume Uni) Décès …   Wikipédia en Français

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”