Austrian school of economics

Austrian school of economics
Body of economic theory developed by several late 19th-century Austrian economists.

Carl Menger (1840–1921) published a paper on their new theory of value in 1871. The concept of value was subjective, the source of a product's value being its ability to satisfy human wants. The actual value depended on the utility derived by the consumer from the product in its least important use (marginal utility). The theory was also applied to production and pricing. Other founders of the school included Friedrich von Wieser (1851–1926) and Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (1851–1914). See also opportunity cost; productivity.

* * *

      body of economic theory developed in the late 19th century by Austrian economists who, in determining the value (utility and value) of a product, emphasized the importance of its utility (utility and value) to the consumer. Carl Menger (Menger, Carl) published the new theory of value in 1871, the same year in which English economist William Stanley Jevons (Jevons, William Stanley) independently published a similar theory.

      Menger believed that value is completely subjective: a product's value is found in its ability to satisfy human wants. Moreover, the actual value depends on the product's utility in its least important use (see marginal utility). If the product exists in abundance, it will be used in less-important ways. As the product becomes more scarce, however, the less-important uses are abandoned, and greater utility will be derived from the new least-important use. (This idea relates to one of the most important laws in economics, the law of demand (supply and demand), which says that when the price of something rises, people will demand less of it.)

      This theory of value also supplies an answer to the so-called “diamond-water paradox,” which economist Adam Smith (Smith, Adam) pondered but was unable to solve. Smith noted that, even though life cannot exist without water and can easily exist without diamonds, diamonds are, pound for pound, vastly more valuable than water. The marginal-utility theory of value resolves the paradox. Water in total is much more valuable than diamonds in total because the first few units of water are necessary for life itself. But, because water is plentiful and diamonds are scarce, the marginal value of a pound of diamonds exceeds the marginal value of a pound of water. The idea that value derives from utility contradicted Karl Marx (Marx, Karl)'s labour theory of value, which held that an item's value derives from the labour used to produce it and not from its ability to satisfy human wants.

      The theory of marginal utility was applied to production as well as to consumption. Friedrich von Wieser (Wieser, Friedrich von) based the value of productive resources on their contribution to the final product, recognizing that changes in the amount used of one productive factor would alter the productivity of other factors. He also introduced the concept of opportunity cost: Wieser showed that the cost of a factor of production can be determined by its utility in some alternative use—i.e., an opportunity forgone. The concept of “opportunity cost,” as identified by Wieser, is still widely used in modern economic analysis.

      Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen von) developed marginal-utility (marginal utility) analysis into a theory of price. Böhm-Bawerk is best known, however, for his work on capital and interest, in which he emphasized the role of time in determining the value of goods. He viewed interest as the charge for the use of capital—a compensation to the owner for abstaining from present consumption. The rate of interest was determined by the size of the labour force, the amount of a community's capital, and the possibility of increasing productivity through methods of production.

      The two leading Austrian economists of the 20th century were Ludwig von Mises (Mises, Ludwig von) and Friedrich A. Hayek (Hayek, F.A.). Mises (in the 1920s) and Hayek (in the 1940s) both showed that a complex economy cannot be rationally planned because true market prices are absent. As a result, the information critical for centralized planning cannot be obtained.

* * *


Universalium. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно сделать НИР?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Austrian School of Economics —    Classical economic theory based its theory of value on the costs that went into the production of a given item. The Austrian School of Economics, led by Eugen von Böhm Bawerk (1851–1914), Karl von Menger (1840–1921), and Friedrich von Wieser… …   Historical dictionary of Austria

  • Austrian School — Part of a series on Libertarianism Austrian School …   Wikipedia

  • London School of Economics — Not to be confused with School of Economic Science. London School of Economics and Political Science Motto Latin: Rerum cognoscere causas Motto in English To Understand the Causes of Things …   Wikipedia

  • Chicago school of economics — Part of the series on Chicago school of economics Movements Libertarianism Neoliberalism Neoconservatism …   Wikipedia

  • Stockholm School of Economics — Infobox University name =Stockholm School of Economics native name =Handelshögskolan i Stockholm latin name = motto = established =1909 type =Private city =Stockholm state = country =Sweden enrollment = undergrad =1,900 postgrad = doctoral =230… …   Wikipedia

  • Historical school of economics — The Historical school of economics was an approach to academic economics and to public administration that emerged in 19th century in Germany, and held sway there until well into the 20th century.The Historical school held that history was the… …   Wikipedia

  • List of Austrian School economists — The economists aligned with the Austrian School are sometimes colloquially called the Austrians even though not all hold Austrian citizenship, and not all economists from Austria subscribe to the ideas of the Austrian School. Austrian economists… …   Wikipedia

  • economics — /ek euh nom iks, ee keuh /, n. 1. (used with a sing. v.) the science that deals with the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services, or the material welfare of humankind. 2. (used with a pl. v.) financial considerations;… …   Universalium

  • Economics — This article is about the social science. For other uses, see Economics (disambiguation). For a topical guide to this subject, see Outline of economics. Economics …   Wikipedia

  • Economics of global warming — This article describes the economics of global warming and climate change. Contents 1 Definitions 2 Climate change science 3 Scenarios 4 Trends and projections …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”